For many years hospitals and physicians have been
paid by insurance companies for each procedure they perform. This may seem reasonable since every
procedure performed, from discussing a patient's disease to performing the most
complicated surgery, requires resources.
However, it creates a perverse set of financial incentives for physicians
and hospital systems. Sicker patients
lead to more procedures which lead to more revenue. The financial incentive is to make patients
sicker!
Physicians and hospital administrators recognize the
wrongness of this incentive structure.
Only criminally anti-social individuals would actively pursue
"upselling" as a legitimate means of increasing hospital
revenue. Therefore, in order to obscure
and minimize the effect of this financial incentive, physicians are shielded
from the costs of the procedures they perform and hospital administrations typically
do not monitor the health of their patient population.
There is a movement in healthcare to impose
financial incentives for healthcare providers to make patients healthier. Recent changes in (1) the rules by which the
Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services (CMS) must operate and (2) federal
law regarding the implementation of electronic health records, are beginning to
make this change a reality.
As of 2012 CMS can work with hospitals or groups of
physicians to create "Accountable
Care Organizations" (ACOs). Under this payment structure, care providers
are given a fixed fee for each patient for whom they are responsible; if they
can save money in the care of that patient they get to pocket the savings. This is similar to the fee structure of
Health Maintenance Organizations that were reviled by patients in the 1980's
because they were financially incentivized to minimize patient
interactions.
There are some key differences which, if taken
advantage of, can lead to a different outcome for ACOs. First, with ACOs and other "risk
bearing" healthcare organizations there are penalties when patients do not
do well. This leads to a question into
which statistics can offer insight; since
everybody is different, what does it mean for a patient to be doing well? Second,
the opportunities for communication between hospital systems and patients have
vastly improved since the 1980’s. Try
searching for “frustrated
with hospital” on twitter and you will readily see
that communication from the patient to the hospital is already very robust. Third, due to the Affordable Care Act, there
is a growing percentage of the population who are directly responsible for
choosing their own health insurance. It
is natural to demand the most expensive insurance from one’s employer if a
choice of health insurance provider is not part of the hiring process. However, when an individual is deciding
between plans with vastly different prices, choosing a plan that encourages maximizing
the number of procedures no longer seems like the obvious choice – it shouldn’t
have been anyway.
In addition to changing fee structures, as of 2012
healthcare organizations are required
to maintain electronic medical records. The original intention of this law was to
encourage the free exchange of health information between providers in order to
minimize duplication of effort; if a patient has an x-ray at one hospital, it
should not be repeated the next day if they show up at a different
hospital. In practice, this objective has
not yet been realized because every hospital has its own EMR and those systems
are not interoperable – even if they were purchased from the same vendor. However, what has been created is a vast
trove of data about the health of individual patients. The
potential of this huge amount of data to affect all aspects of healthcare
cannot be overstated. In particular,
risk bearing hospital systems now have both the financial incentives and the
necessary data to track the health of their patient population and be proactive
in the treatment of disease. Successful physician-statistician
collaborations are needed to turn this data into information that hospital
systems can act upon.
Driving uptake of IT and Statistics in Healthcare
The strongest and earliest driver encouraging
hospitals to implement electronic medical records originates from CMS in the
form of a couple of different penalties.
The “meaningful use” requirement is being implemented in three
increasingly strict phases (phase
1,
phase
2
and phase
3). Those hospitals that are deemed not to be
utilizing their electronic medical records in a meaningful way will be
penalized, beginning in 2015, with a 1% decrease in CMS payouts. The penalty increases by 1% yearly up to a
total of 5% for consistent failure to achieve meaningful use – tens of millions
of dollars for hospitals with large Medicare and Medicaid populations. Most of the meaningful use definitions require
solutions that are straightforward even if they are technically complicated to
implement. As of early 2014, I am not
aware of any “meaningful use” applications that involve statistical solutions,
though I can imagine improvements to the current versions that might. Here
I discuss a statistical approach to identifying homogeneous groups of patients
(one of the elements of meaningful use in phase 2). Whether improvements like these are
financially viable will depend heavily on the way that financial incentives are
structured for hospitals.
The second penalty
(again a 1% incrementally increasing penalty), and the one that has led the
industry to seek out statistical solutions, is a reduction in payment for
hospitals with too many patients who are readmitted within 30 days of
discharge. There has been an explosion
of statistical models attempting to predict early readmission – there is an open
access survey in JAMA for those who want greater
detail. To my knowledge, all of the
models attempting to accomplish this are logistic regressions which, in their
final form, rely on a clearly defined set of data (independent
variables) with which to make predictions. Implementing these models in practice is
challenging because electronic records do not follow fixed standards, patient
populations vary significantly between hospitals, and every hospital record
system is plagued by missing and incorrectly coded data. Finally, it is not
always clear how far back into a record one must go. A typical statistical approach to modeling
the time varying state of a patient is to assume that all the relevant information
for predicting the future is available in the present (see hidden Markov
model and memorylessness). However, if two patients come to the hospital
with skin infections, and one was diagnosed years earlier with diabetes, the
severity of their infection and their chances of returning within 30 days are
very different.
I have described some of the disruptive changes that
hospitals are undergoing as a result of changing incentives and the
availability of electronic health records.
The availability of this data will disrupt healthcare delivery at all
levels; insurance companies, contract research organizations, pharma,
regulators and consumers are all seeing (and will continue to see)
disruption.
Perhaps the most exciting thing for statisticians is
the availability of a vast array of statistical challenges in the healthcare
industry that are financially viable, able to tolerate uncertainty and just
downright fun to work on. We will likely
never get to a point where computers can be trusted to make medical decisions
for patients, but a tricorder
reminiscent of Star Trek might be just around the corner,
and even a 1% increase in efficiency for the half-trillion dollar drug
discovery industry would be tremendously valuable.
No comments:
Post a Comment